Copyright & Fair-use Agreement
UNLV Special Collections provides copies of materials to facilitate private study, scholarship, or research. Material not in the public domain may be used according to fair use of copyrighted materials as defined by copyright law. Please cite us.
Please note that UNLV may not own the copyright to these materials and cannot provide permission to publish or distribute materials when UNLV is not the copyright holder. The user is solely responsible for determining the copyright status of materials and obtaining permission to use material from the copyright holder and for determining whether any permissions relating to any other rights are necessary for the intended use, and for obtaining all required permissions beyond that allowed by fair use.
Read more about our reproduction and use policy.
I agree.Information
Digital ID
Permalink
Details
Member of
More Info
Rights
Digital Provenance
Publisher
Transcription
Public Utility Property the public is entitled to demand is that no more be exacted from it for the use of a public highway than the services rendered by it are reasonably worth. A reading of the prevailing and dissenting opinions of the Supreme Court from the time of Smyth v. Ames to the present day, in my opinion, will demonstrate that the above-quoted rule did not create certainty in the fixing of rates but tended to create confusion. The most cutting criticisms of this rule are to be found in the many vigorous dissenting opinions rendered by various justices of the Supreme Court. Efforts to Interpret and A p p ly the Standards of Smyth v. Ames T he rule having been prescribed, regulatory bodies and the lower courts were placed in the position of conforming' to the standards laid down in that rule. So in 1913 the Supreme Court, in Simpson v. Shepard, 230 U. S. 352, 433-435, 454-461, 57 L. ed. 1511, 1555-1556, 1564-1566, commonly referred to as the Minnesota Rate cases, held that the basis of calculation in arriving at the valuation of the property of a public utility is the fair value of the property used for the convenience of the public, and cited with approval Smyth v. Ames. It was there pointed out that the ascertainment of value is not controlled by artificial rules, that it is not a matter of formulas, but there must be a reasonable judgment, having its basis in a proper consideration of all relevant facts (page 434). The Court conceded that the ratemaking power is a legislative power and necessarily implies a range of legislative discretion. The Court conceded that it did not sit as a board of revision to substitute its judgment for that of the legislature or of the lawfully constituted commission to which the legislature had delegated its rate-making powers (page 433). Impliedly, the Court followed the so-called eminent domain rule and enforced the Smyth v. Ames rule. While the Court announced that the fair value of the property of a public utility is the criterion, it also held that as applied to land the fair average market value of similar land in the vicinity should be the standard (page 455). Differences and Difficulties as to Valuing Land Devoted to Public Uses There may be some technical difference in the rule of fair value and the particular rule applied to the valuation of land in this case. This is said because some courts and commissions have made a distinction between land and other property owned by a public utility in applying valuation rules and formulae. It is nothing unusual for a regulatory body to value property other than land on a cost basis and value land on a fair market value basis. In order to understand the principle of land valuation laid down in Simpson v. Shepard, one must consider the background and historical setting applicable to the controversy involved. The ruling in question was designed to protect the public against exorbitant costs incurred by railroads in acquiring land. The record in that case shows that railroads had acquired land at exorbitant prices by private purchase and were seeking to place such costs in the rate base. The Court sought by its ruling to protect the public from being saddled with these exorbitant land costs incurred by the railroads. The Court held that valuing land at fair average market value wo t Id protect the public and at the same time set a valuation concerning which a public utility could not lawfully complain. It was there pointed out that a railroad company could exercise the power of condemnation and thus avoid exorbitant costs in acquiring land. Apparently, the Court did not consider, or at least did not reflect, the prudent investment principle put forward by Justices Brandeis and Holmes in their concurring opinion in Missouri ex rel. Southwestern Bell Telephone Co. v. Public Service Commission of Missouri, 262 U. S. 276, 289, 67 L. ed. 981, 985, decided in 1923. The Court in the Simpson case very properly observed that it would be unfair to require the rate payer to be subjected to a penalty that flows from imprudent investments made by a public utility (page 454). The Court observed also that, if the property of a public utility had a fair value in excess of the cost to the public utility of that particular property, justice required that the utility receive the benefit by recognizing the fair value instead of the cost. At first blush, this latter view would seem to be a logical corollary of the view that the rate payer should not be penalized by having saddled upon him exorbitant costs incurred by a utility in the acquisition of property. It must be remembered that the Court in the Simpson case was dealing specifically with the attempt by the railroads to obtain recognition, for rate-fixing purposes, of exorbitant costs incurred by them in acquiring land. No question was there presented of property of a value in excess of what the property had cost the railroads. The question for decision had to do with excessive cost over reasonable value, and the Court decided that such excessive cost could not be placed upon the backs of the rate-payers. I.ater on, we will refer more specifically to the prudent in- * vestment principle of valuation put forward by Justices Brandeis and Holmes. I will concede that any cost formula used in valuing property of a public utility must necessarily be qualified by the requirement that the cost must be reasonable. Particularly as applied to land, the Court in the Simpson case devised the rule there laid down to overcome an unfair situation, as applied to the ratepayer, which could have been overcome more rationally, in my opinion, by adopting the prudent investment theory, with the implied qualification that the cost of the land must be reasonable and, if not reasonable, be revised to a reasonable figure before being recognized in the rate base. Obviously, if cost of property should be taken for valuation purposes, without any qualification, one 1 0 9 8 American Bar Association Journal